The Hugest tax cut in US history: Should that be the goal?

The President on June 8th said, "We have also proposed a historic tax cut — biggest in the history of our country, by the way".  Although details about the plan await, an analysis by Jerry Tempalski of the US Treasury provides some indication of the potential size of the tax cut: at least -2.89% of GDP, the prior record from the Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981.

A record US tax cut would reduce revenues over the next ten years by at least $7.3 trillion, at -2.89% of GDP.  However, the 1981 Tax Act That Act phased in a 23% reduction in individual tax rates, provided extremely accelerated depreciation of capital assets, and indexed individual tax rate brackets by inflation starting four years later.   By the fourth year after enactment, the reduction was -4.15% of GDP and probably still growing.  If the six out-years are at -4.15% of GDP, the President's total tax cut would be over $9.3 trillion over ten years. 

The President’s FY18 budget (Table S-2) claims there will be 10-year $2.1 trillion budget “effect of economic feedback”, some of which will be from tax “reform” as well as from other government initiatives.  Thus, the dynamic macroeconomic effects will only offset a small portion of the huge deficit increase from the tax cut yet to be proposed in sufficient detail to make an actual estimate of its total cost or its economic effects. 

Instead of trying to set a new record on the size of tax reductions, any tax change should focus on the future needs of the American citizens, and establish a tax system that effectively promotes economic growth, is simpler and also fairer. 

Tom Neubig

Cash flow taxation and “excess” (but still marginal) returns

Setting aside the issue of border adjustability, the cash-flow tax on domestic producers would replace the current CIT’s tax on total corporate equity income with a business tax on so-called “excess” returns.  To see this, consider expensing of business investment is similar to a traditional Individual Retirement Account (IRA) deduction.  A traditional IRA provides an immediate tax benefit that is equivalent to exempting the expected “normal” return on the retirement savings.  The present value of the immediate tax savings offsets the expected present value of the future taxes on the payouts of both the principal and expected investment return.  But since all future payouts are subject to tax, any “excess” capital returns would be taxed in the future.  Unlike a Roth IRA that provides no upfront deduction but exempts all future payouts, the traditional IRA (expensing) taxes “excess" returns.  

Expensing eliminates the so-called “normal” return to capital, but a recent US Treasury empirical study found that three-quarters of corporate income was "excess" returns.  (See Nov. 21, 2016 blog on "normal" and "excess" returns.) Businesses and investors aren’t taking risks and exerting significant efforts to earn “normal” returns, which often are equated to government bond rates.  Businesses and investors are still concerned about taxes on "excess" returns.  Taxes on “excess” returns can reduce the expected return below their high hurdles rates that reflect risk and entrepreneurial effort.  

The return may be "excess" but it isn't necessarily "infra-marginal" to investors and entrepreneurs. That is why many corporations were more interested in a lower corporate tax rate than expensing after a similar tax reform proposal was made in 2005.

Tom Neubig

Border adjustability will affect imports and exports

Border adjustability in the House Ways and Means Republicans’ destination-based cash-flow tax reform proposal will not result in an immediate and full offsetting exchange rate change as recently claimed by Martin Feldstein, significantly increasing the value of the US dollar relative to foreign currencies.  As noted in the January 6, 2017 blog, Feldstein made a different argument in 1990. 

Alan Viard has made a persuasive case that border adjustability will not permanently change the trade balance, given the assumption that the present value of imports and exports must balance over the life of a country!  However, in the near term, Alan notes that a new and/or non-comprehensive border-adjusted tax can cause sectorial changes discouraging some imports and encouraging some exports.  The magnitude and distribution of those changes need more analysis rather than assuming they won't happen. 

Alan also emphasizes that an increase in the US dollar will have a significant transition effect reducing the value of Americans’ holdings of foreign assets.  That wealth effect would reduce the well-being of American households and should also be subject to additional analysis. Both the trade and wealth effects may be offset by other advantages of the proposed tax reform, but should be explicitly considered by our policymakers.

Tom Neubig

Fiscal federalism affects multinational decisions: new approach to winners & losers?

The recent news of Carrier Corporation’s choice of locating jobs in Indiana vs. Mexico highlights that state taxes also matter in multinational corporations’ investment decisions. As noted in our January 6th blog, origin-based US state and local businesses taxes, such as property taxes and sales taxes on business inputs, are greater than the US federal corporate income tax.  Those origin-based taxes affect business location decisions.

What is newsworthy about the Carrier decision is that it may signal a growing recognition by the U.S. federal government of the importance of state and local business taxes in U.S. business location decisions (“competitiveness”).  The Carrier decision was significantly based on additional state tax incentives.  The negotiations were the result of the Twitter-pulpit of President-elect Trump and his Vice-President Elect and then-current Indiana Governor Pence.

From the perspective of state government policymakers the Carrier negotiations may be seen as a mixed blessing.  States have always strongly defended their "independence" from federal involvement in state tax policy. The new federal Administration may result in the federal government attempting to have more influence on which states benefit from new business jobs and investment.  In addition to choosing winners or losers among businesses, the federal government may exercise more influence in choosing which states are winners or losers.  States may be understandably concerned if this happens. 

Multistate corporations' extensive domestic tax legislative activities highlight the importance of state and local taxes to business.  These have included on-going challenges to assessed values of taxable business property at the local level, support for reduced sales taxation at business input at the state level, and advocacy for lower rates and more generous general as well as targeted tax credits or incentives.  Individual negotiated "deals" already common in many states may occur more often as a result of a presidential Twitter blast.   

The new federal Administration may signal a more proactive policy of encouraging particular business behaviors, such as locating economic activity in the U.S.  It may also signal a stronger federal role in the U.S. fiscal federalism, contrary to Republicans’ conventional backing of greater states’ rights, at least in the area of tax and business incentives.

Robert Cline and Tom Neubig

Extending OECD's Tax and Growth Analysis to Inclusive Growth

Important new OECD Working Paper (WP), "Tax Design for Inclusive Growth," by four former colleagues at the Centre for Tax Policy and Administration's Tax Policy and Statistics Division. The WP adds critical new dimensions to the prior OECD Tax and Growth work. No longer focused just on economic growth, tax policy and administration designs for both equity and efficiency considerations are discussed.  Many areas for future research are noted.

An important insight highlighted is when tax avoidance and evasion opportunities are closed, the supposed "mobility" of capital is reduced, thus weakening the argument for lower tax rates for "mobile" capital. The OECD/G20 BEPS Project, which will reduce corporate tax avoidance (see OECD BEPS website), and the establishment of a single common global standard on automatic exchange of financial account information  (see OECD AEOI website), while will reduce personal tax evasion, are important tax system changes that will positively affect tax policy for inclusive growth.

Tom Neubig

Future Research Issues for Better Understanding BEPS

Many researchers may have missed a significant contribution of the BEPS Action 11 report identifying important areas for future economic research.  These are some of the questions that arose in the course of the progress made in measuring BEPS.  A good analysis often raises more questions than answers.  Hopefully this report provided both. See the text of the BEPS Action 11 report on pages 122-124 of Chapter 3. 

"Future areas for economic research to better measure the scale and economic impact of BEPS with better data

The mandate for Action 11 included developing an economic analysis of the scale and impact of BEPS (including spillover effects across countries) and actions to address it. This chapter summarises the current understanding of the scale and impact of BEPS based on academic studies, other international organisations’ analyses, as well as some new OECD research. Progress is being made in better understanding BEPS and countermeasures, and the economic analysis show that BEPS is significant and affects many economic decisions of both taxpayers and governments. The issue of BEPS and appropriate geographic allocation of income and expenses relative to measures of value creating activities is important not only to the current corporate income tax, but also would affect other taxes proposed by some academics such as a business cash-flow tax or a comprehensive business income tax.

The current body of empirical research into the fiscal and economic impacts of BEPS demonstrates that the stakes are high, but there is still much further research needed to be undertaken. ... A number of areas for future research beyond the Action 11 mandate but which will add to the understanding of BEPS and MNEs are highlighted, since better data alone will not be sufficient for the best possible analysis of BEPS.

The following are some of the areas where additional analysis is needed:

·      The prevalence and intensity of BEPS. How pervasive are BEPS behaviours? Is BEPS limited to a small number of MNEs or more widespread? Are some MNEs more intensively exploiting BEPS than other MNEs, and if so why (e.g. costs of tax planning, corporate governance, risk profile)? Would largely unrestricted BEPS encourage smaller MNEs to start engaging in BEPS and encourage domestic companies to go global for the BEPS tax benefits?

·      Differences in the profitability of MNEs vs. comparable domestic entities. Are there inherent economic differences between MNEs and domestic entities which make comparisons of ETR difficult? If so, how can competitiveness between MNEs and domestic entities be evaluated?

·      Factors contributing to group profitability. What contributes to the profitability of a global consolidated MNE? How much can be explained by tangible capital, labour and/or sales compared to other factors such as different types of intangible assets, public infrastructure, country risk diversification, etc.

·      Factors contributing to affiliate profitability. What contributes to the profitability of individual MNE entities? How can functions, assets and risks be incorporated in future analyses of BEPS, since they are the basis of arm’s length pricing? How much can be explained simply by tangible capital, labour and/or sales compared to other factors such as the intangible assets of their global MNE, public infrastructure, labour force qualities and stability in a country, etc.? How can these other factors which may change over time be incorporated more fully than just dummy variables?

·      Other tax factors in location decisions. Corporate taxes are only one source- based tax affecting location decisions. How do these other business taxes affect MNEs’ tax decisions? How can measures of profit shifting separate the effects of non-BEPS tax preferences from BEPS?

·      Effects of uncertainty, reputation and compliance costs, and disclosure. Companies face the equivalent of implicit taxes from uncertainty, reputation and compliance costs. Can these be measured and included in the economic analysis of taxes and BEPS? What effects do disclosures to tax administrations have?

·      Mobility of different types of labour and capital. How mobile are different forms of real economic activity, such as top level executives, R&D scientists, production workers, back-office workers, buildings, equipment, different types of intangible assets, etc.?

·      Governments’ strategic behaviours. How do different institutional settings affect countries’ co-operative versus competitive behaviours? How multilateral do agreements need to be to achieve effective co-operative outcomes?

The analysis of BEPS and countermeasures has advanced since 2013, providing more evidence of BEPS and insights into specific BEPS channels and potential effects of BEPS countermeasures. As analysts can only observe the current world with BEPS, any analysis of BEPS and countermeasures must estimate a comparison point, whether it be a world without BEPS, a future world without co-ordinated multilateral action, or a future world with proposed countermeasures. Future analysis of BEPS, MNEs’ BEPS behaviours, and tax competition with improved estimation methodologies are needed to complement improvements in the available data relevant for analysing BEPS and BEPS countermeasures."

Tom Neubig and Bob Cline